




Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Prepare for your exams
Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points to download
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Community
Ask the community for help and clear up your study doubts
Discover the best universities in your country according to Docsity users
Free resources
Download our free guides on studying techniques, anxiety management strategies, and thesis advice from Docsity tutors
An analysis of the impact of government spending on GDP and unemployment using the goods market model. It discusses how an increase in government spending leads to an increase in GDP through the multiplier effect and how unemployment rate is affected by changes in the labor force and employment numbers. It also explains the concept of nominal and real GDP and the importance of the choice of base year for calculating the growth rate of real GDP.
What you will learn
Typology: Summaries
1 / 8
This page cannot be seen from the preview
Don't miss anything!
Posted: Monday, September 12, 2005 Due: Wednesday, September 21, 2005
Part I. True/False/Uncertain Justify your answer with a short argument.
UNCERTAIN. When the government purchases goods or services, it counts as a part of G. Therefore, in the goods market model, when G increases by $100, GDP increases by at least $ million. It increases by $100 million only if the multiplier is equal to one, meaning that the marginal propensity to consume is 0. If the marginal propensity to consumer is bigger than 0, which is a more realistic situation, then the multiplier is bigger than one and GDP increases by multiplier*$100 million.
TRUE. In the goods market model, an increase in unemployment insurance benefits amounts to a decrease in T (since T is taxes paid minus government transfers received by consumers). Thus, disposable income increases, which implies that consumption goes up and that GDP increases (with a multiplier effect).
FALSE. Goods Market Eqm → Y = C + I + G Y = [c 0 + c 1 Y - c 1 T] + I + G
Y = ] 1
− c 1
[c 0 + I + G - c 1 T ]
multiplier → ] 1
− c 1
If 0 < c 1 < 1 → ] 1
− c 1
If the marginal propensity to consume is less than 1, it means that people consume less than 100% of their disposable income. It also implies that the multiplier is greater 1. The fact that T = 0, G = 0, and NX=0 is irrelevant.
FALSE. Real GDP changes only when the quantity of final goods and services produced changes. Nominal GDP changes when either the quantity and/or the price of final goods and services produced changes. So, it is possible for an economy to experience an increase of real GDP (if the quantity of final goods and services increase) but experience a decrease of nominal GDP (if the decrease in prices offsets the increase in quantity of goods and services).
Uncertain.
Inflation usually leads to distortions because all prices and wages do not rise proportionately during inflationary periods. So, inflation affects income distribution and may lead to uncertainties about the future which is considered not good. (If all prices rise proportionally it is called pure inflation and it would just be a minor inconvenience.)
FALSE. Growth in nominal GDP per capita is not the best way of measuring changes in material living standards because it does not adjust for inflation. In an economy with a high inflation will experience an increase in nominal GDP even if the real amount of goods and services produced decreases. Real GDP per capital is a better measure of material living standards.
FALSE.
GDP Deflator = gives the average price of output (final goods produced in the economy)
CPI = Consumer Price Index Average price of consumption (goods people consume)
PPI = Producer Price Index Prices of domestically produced goods in manufacturing, mining, agriculture, fishing, forestry, and electric utility industries.
It is hard to say which one is better or more “correct” in measuring inflation. Each index gives us different information. It depends mostly on what you are interested in knowing. If one wants to know how the price level of goods produced in the US is changing, then the GDP deflator would give the most accurate picture. On the other hand, if one was interested in knowing how the price level of consumer goods was changing over time, then CPI would be the best.
Part III. NATIONAL ACCOUNTS (GDP, GDP DEFLATOR & CPI)
For part II, assume the following:
year
freshmen Price nominal GDP real GDP real GDP (quantity) (Tuition) (1950$) (2000$)
1950 100 $1,000 $100,000 $100,000 $2,000, 2000 800 $20,000 $16,000,000 $800,000 $16,000, 2001 1000 $21,000 $21,000,000 $1,000,000 $20,000, 2002 1100 $22,000 $24,200,000 $1,100,000 $22,000, 2003 1000 $24,000 $24,000,000 $1,000,000 $20,000, 2004 1200 $31,000 $37,200,000 $1,200,000 $24,000,
How to calculate nominal GDP: nominal GDP (^) t = quantity (^) t * price (^) t How to calculate real GDP: real GDP (^) t = quantity (^) t * price (^) baseyear
How to calculate the growth rate: Growth rate of Xt = * 100 ( 1 )
() ( 1 ) ⎟
−
− t
t t X
year nominal GDP real GDP real GDP growth growth (1950$) growth (2000$) ( % ) ( % ) ( % )
2001 31.3 25.0 25. 2002 15.2 10.0 10. 2003 -0.8 -9.1 -9. 2004 55.0 20.0 20.
No, the choice of base year is not important here. See answers to part 4. Real GDP is constructed as the sum of the quantities of final goods times constant prices. (A base year is chosen). So, it tells us how the quantity of finals goods changes over time and not price. Only the change in quantity affects real GDP.
The base year chosen is sort of like a choice of unit of measurement. For example, whether one measures one’s weight in pounds or kilograms does not affect one’s actual weight. Therefore, the choice of base year, does not affect the growth of real GDP.
If there is only one good, the price drops out of the formula for the growth rate of real GDP:
Growth rate of Xt = * 100 * 100
( 1 )
() ( 1 ) ( 1 )
() ( 1 ) ⎟
−
− −
− t
t t b t
b t b t Q
, where Xt = Pb *Qt
This is why the choice of base year doesn’t matter. However, if there are two goods in the economy, real GDP is calculated as X (^) t = P1b *Q1t + P2b *Q2t , which implies that the prices don’t drop out of the growth formula since P1b and P2b can of course be different. Thus, if there are more than two goods, the choice of base year does matter.
Inflation GDP deflator rate (%)
2000 100 2001 105 5. 2002 110 4. 2003 120 9. 2004 155 29.
(page 30-31)
GDP deflator = t
t realGDP
nGDP = Pt
Inflation rate = * 100 ( 1 )
() ( 1 ) ⎟
−
− t
t t P
Private Saving : S = YD – C = 800 – 700 = 100
Public Saving : (T – G ) = (200 – 250) = -50 (Budget Deficit of $50 million)
Investment : I = S + (T – G ) = sum of private and public saving I = 100 – 50 = 50 (Consumers can either lend to the government or the private sector (companies). When the government runs a budget deficit, it must borrow from consumers, so the budget deficit crowds out Investment. Here, consumers saved a total of $100 million, but $ million was lend to the government, leaving only $50 million for the private sector.)
mpc = marginal propensity to consume gives the effect of an additional dollar of disposable income on consumption. For example, if mpc = c 1 = 0.3, this means that $0.30 of an additional $1 of disposable income will be consumed, and $0.70 will be saved. mpc = coefficient on YD.
In this problem, mpc = c 1 = 0.6. For every $1 additional disposable income increase, $0.60 will be consumed. Disposable income is the income after taxes.
mps = (1 – c 1 ) = marginal propensity to save mps = 1-0.6 = 0.
mpc + mps = 1 For another $1 income, you either save or consume. mpc = proportion you consume mps = the proportion you save Must add up to 1 (or 100%)
Goods Market Eqm → Y = C + I + G Y = [c 0 + c 1 Y - c 1 T] + I + G
Y = ] 1
− c 1
[c 0 + I + G - c 1 T ]
Multiplier → ] 1
− c 1
Autonomous Spending → [c 0 + I + G - c 1 T ] = 400
Autonomous spending is the part of demand for goods that does not depend on output. The multiplier tells us how much equilibrium output will change for a given change in autonomous spending. For example, if investment increases by 500, then the equilibrium output will rise by 1,250 (500 *2.5). Why? First, investment increases by 500. Then, this increase in I increases Z (total demand). When demand increases, production must also increase to maintain equilibrium. This means that Y increases. When Y increases, Yd will increase. When disposable income increases, C increases. C increase will result in yet a higher Z since C is a part of Z (total demand). But, when Z increases, Y must also increase to match it if in equilibrium, and so on. This process continues. (Please see textbook for detailed description)
When G increases by 100, then autonomous spending increases by 100. Since the multiplier is 2.5, the equilibrium output will increase by 250. (ZZ and the 45^0 line will now intersect at 1250) Y* = 1250.
Therefore, disposable income will rise by 250 since YD = (Y-T). Consumption will rise by 150 since mpc is 0.6. 150 = 0.6 * (250)
Y = Z (slope = 1)
autonomous spending 400
new autonomous spending