



Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Prepare for your exams
Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points to download
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Community
Ask the community for help and clear up your study doubts
Discover the best universities in your country according to Docsity users
Free resources
Download our free guides on studying techniques, anxiety management strategies, and thesis advice from Docsity tutors
The phenomenon in behavioural science for humans to behave with more kindness and fairness than would be the case if they behaved rationally.
Typology: Lecture notes
1 / 5
This page cannot be seen from the preview
Don't miss anything!
Resources for Courses
The phenomenon in behavioural science for humans to behave with more kindness and fairness than would be the case if they behaved rationally. The ultimatum game is a good example of the principle. Imagine a situation in which two people are paired up; one participant is given £20 and asked to split it between the two of them in any way that they like. The rational decision (i.e. optimising) is to split it 19: but this rarely happens, with the split usually being closer to 10:10. Altruism is often linked to the concept of inequity aversion i.e. humans do not like unequal outcomes. Whilst this is usually seen as positive, it can also result in a negative outcome e.g. a person being willing to forego a gain / reward if it means that someone else won’t gain an even better reward.
The use of (usually) irrelevant information as a reference point for helping to make an estimate of an unknown piece of information. In other words, people use an “anchor point” of an event or a value that they know in order to make a decision or estimate. Behavioural scientists describe this as a cognitive bias.
This concept is closely linked to that of bounded rationality. Rationally, and according to neoclassical economic theory, consumers know when the price of a good/service exceeds the marginal utility they gain from consuming that good/service – in this rational world of homo economicus, consumers stop consuming. In reality, though, there is plenty of evidence to suggest that consumers often do not stop consuming even when it makes sense to stop – think about over-eating, excessive investment in a particular stock or share and so on. Many behavioural scientists link bounded self-control to the concept of hyperbolic discounting i.e. valuing the present much more than the future, and making decisions that their “future self” would not like. This can help to explain, for example, people’s inability to save effectively for retirement.
The idea that the cognitive, decision-making capacity of humans cannot be fully rational because of a number of limits that we face. These limits include:
The default choice or default option is the option that a consumer “selects” if he or she does nothing. Studies have shown that consumers rarely change the default settings. So, the nature of the default option strongly affects consumer behaviour. Therefore, if the default option or setting is changed, then consumer behaviour will change.
Default
Choice
This term stems from the Nobel-prize winning work of Daniel Kahnemann, who is best known for his work Thinking, Fast and Slow. System 1 thinking is fast, sub-conscious and automatic. System 2 thinking is slow, controlled and conscious. We tend to use System 2 thinking when the decision is really important, is highly personal to us and when our decision may have a large impact on other people.
Dual-system
theory
This refers to a rigid pattern of behaviour followed by a person. For example, it could refer to the subconscious purchase of identical items each week, or the pattern followed by someone who always lights up a cigarette, without thinking, when they make a cup of coffee. Habit is often linked with System 1 thinking (see Dual-system theory). It is also often linked with the idea of the status quo bias, when people stick with a previous decision, even if it is no longer the most appropriate decision.
Habit
A phenomenon in which individuals act collectively as part of a group, often making decisions as a group that they would not make as an individual. There are 2 generally accepted explanations of herd behaviour. Firstly, the social pressure to conform means that individuals want to be accepted – and this means behaving in the same way as others, even if that behaviour goes against your natural instincts. Secondly, individuals find it hard to believe that a large group could be wrong (“2 heads are better than 1”) and follow the group’s behaviour in the mistaken belief that the group knows something that the individual doesn’t. We sometimes also see this described as the bandwagon effect or groupthink. In short, herd behaviour is about making a decision based on the behaviour of others.
Herding /
herd
behaviour
In general terms, a heuristic is a method or technique that people use to help them make a decision or solve a problem more quickly. We often use the phrase rule of thumb to mean the same thing. The outcome from using the heuristic may not be perfect or optimised, but is usually “good enough”. The term was developed, along with bounded rationality and satisficing, by the cognitive scientist Herbert Simon.
Heuristics
A situation or scenario in which people must make a decision in advance with respect to whether they wish to participate in a particular action – they are required by law to make that choice. These decisions are usually “public policy” decisions e.g. deciding whether to donate your organs when you die, deciding whether to make a “living will” etc.
Mandated
choice
A technique used by choice architects in which someone is persuaded to make a decision based on negative consequences e.g. if you choose to park in that space then there is a chance that your car could be towed.
Negative
framing
A technique by which consumption can be reduced by packaging something into smaller amounts. When something (e.g. money, a packet of crisps, sweets) are packaged into separate, smaller packages, then consumers face more decision points which can slow the rate of spending or consumption.
Partitioning
Because of the existence of bounded rationality, consumers can find it really difficult to make effective decisions when the number of choices or options is large; this may result in them failing to make any decision. Therefore, restricting the number of available choices may be more likely to cause consumers to act and actually make a decision, resulting in a more efficient outcome.
Restricted
Choice
A phenomenon in which the demand curve for a good changes shape dramatically once the price of the good is zero. Standard economics cannot explain the psychological power of a good that is free!
Zero price
effect