



Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Prepare for your exams
Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points to download
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Community
Ask the community for help and clear up your study doubts
Discover the best universities in your country according to Docsity users
Free resources
Download our free guides on studying techniques, anxiety management strategies, and thesis advice from Docsity tutors
The Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH). The EMH tries to explain why stock market prices appear to follow a random walk i.e.; that their.
Typology: Study Guides, Projects, Research
1 / 7
This page cannot be seen from the preview
Don't miss anything!
Niall Douglas This paper shall firstly explain the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH), its history and its theoretical justification for explaining empirical evidence. Fundamental problems with the theory are then highlighted, followed by a summary of the most modern approaches to how markets work. The paper concludes that the EMH works by coincidence i.e.; by accident.
The EMH tries to explain why stock market prices appear to follow a random walk i.e.; that their daily variation is a random value following the Gaussian distribution. This random walk of stock market prices had been originally noticed by Bachelier (1900) but had only become widely realised since Kendall (1953), at which point it was considered something rather unusual. The reason that a random walk appeared unusual was because from Neo‐Classical Economic theory (specifically Walrasian General Equilibrium Theory), markets were supposed to approach equilibrium over the medium to long run and they were supposed to do this by tâtonnement (the process of finding the market clearing prices to precisely match supply and demand). Prior to Arrow (1951) and Debreu (1959), it had not yet been realised just how restrictive the assumptions would have to be in order to enable Walrasian equilibrium whilst keeping the system from degenerating into indeterminacy 1. The EMH was originated by Fama (1965) in his PhD thesis, and given its modern three‐type form in Fama (1970). The EMH explains the random walk by assigning its occurrence to uncertainty i.e.; the existence of the future, whereby future events are unknown to or mispredicted by the market. As we now know that determinate Walrasian equilibrium requires perfect knowledge of the future, uncertainty causes substantial long‐term deviations from expected behaviour. There are three main forms of EMH, each becoming successively stronger in implication:
There are many arguments which have been used to discredit the EMH over the decades. Many focus on market anomalies such as the January effect where the price of small‐cap stocks will rise abnormally during the first few days of trading in a new year (Pietranico & Riepe [2004]), or the existence of long‐term successful investors such as Warren Buffet or George Soros, but there are far more problematic prima‐facie problems at a theoretical level. This paper shall concentrate on the three most important of these. Problem 1: Information Asymmetry One obvious requirement of EMH is that new information must circulate around all investors very quickly indeed if even semi‐strong EMH is to be possible. Good information is costly to generate and rapidly loses value as more people learn it (Chen [2005]), so there is an obvious vested interest against the widespread sharing of information. Empirical studies show that good information tends to be hoarded by investors – indeed, often there are even deliberate attempts at disseminating mis‐ information by one investor to other investors! (Akerlof [1970]) Yet the empirical record (Patell & Wolfson [1984]) would suggest that news is incorporated into price within ten minutes despite that substantial disparities in investor access to information exist. This problem of how the market is really so able to adjust its prices so accurately and so quickly when such information asymmetry exists has occupied a lot of recent research which we shall come to shortly. (^2) See Jensen (1968) & Kim (1978).
Some 77% (15,206) of those days saw a movement of 1% or less, showing that the market is generally fairly stable and its movements are consistent with true randomness. Up until around ±1.25% the data remains consistent with a normal distribution, but for larger movements something else happens: Figure 3: Frequency of Movement Figure 3 shows a log‐log histogram of percentage movements with the values predicted by the normal (Gaussian) distribution overlaid on top. As one can see, the chances of a 5.62% or greater movement in a single day should be next to impossible – in fact, its probability is 0.000000008153576 which means it should happen once in every 122,645,573 days i.e.; never during our eighty years. Yet in reality, it happened no less than seventy‐two times which is far more than it should were the EMH valid. Something else is clearly going on here, which we shall come back to shortly.
Sharpe (1970) who contributed so much to the development of the CAPM in Sharpe (1964) (which depends on the EMH) considered the implications of relaxing the assumptions underpinning both theories: “The consequence of accommodating such aspects of reality are likely to be disastrous in terms of the usefulness of the resulting theory ... The capital market line no longer exists. Instead, there is a capital market curve – linear over some ranges, perhaps, but becoming flatter as [risk] increases over other ranges. Moreover, there is no single optimal combination of risky securities; the preferred combination depends on the investors’ preferences ... The demise of the capital market line is followed immediately by that of the security market line. The theory is in a shambles” (Sharpe 1970) 1 10 100 1000 10000 0.10% 0.18% 0.32% 0.56% 1.00% 1.78% 3.16% 5.62% 10.00% 17.78% 31.62% Log‐Log Graph of Dow Jones Daily Movement 1st October 1928 to 5th April 2007 Real World Normal Distribution
This is pretty damming stuff, especially from someone as eminent as W.F. Sharpe. It means that these assumptions are domain assumptions i.e.; assumptions required to make a theory valid and in the absence of which the theory is no longer true. This strongly implies that EMH, and CAPM, just happens to fit the data by luck for certain ranges of price movement, but that in fact other factors are at work. This fits with our empirical comparison to the normal distribution above. So what is actually going on then? This is moving away from the EMH, so I won’t spend much time on it but it is worth considering alternatives to the EMH. There are two main categories: (i) Behavioural Finance, which comes from a background of cognitive psychology and (ii) Econophysics, which applies theories and methods originally developed by physicists in order to solve problems in Economics, usually those including uncertainties or stochastic elements and non‐linear dynamics. EMH holds that investors objectively consider information about investment opportunities and that because new information arrives randomly, it generates random movements in the expected future prospects of firms. It does not consider that investors are primarily interested in what other investors are doing, which makes sense if all investors are supposed to commonly agree on the valuations of prices (through arriving at equilibrium). Behavioural Finance takes this opposite approach: that investors are primarily concerned with what other investors do and that the underlying fundamentals of their investments are of secondary importance. This explains the much larger daily movements in price than a normal distribution would permit and the irrationality of speeding up a bull market when everyone knows it will crash soon – the self‐reinforcing feedback loops generate such abnormal behaviour through runaway effect. Econophysics goes far further than that again however. It explains that the “random walk” of prices isn’t actually random at all but is in fact a non‐linear power distribution i.e.; a property of a chaotic fractal system – which tends toward Gaussian behaviour (apparent pure randomness) when not activated 4. As Ormerod (1998) reports, any biological system is a fractal system and therefore exhibits chaotic behaviour with allometric scaling. This is a very new and unorthodox research area with heavy mathematics but papers I reviewed for this papers include ‘The statistical properties of the volatility of price fluctuations’ by Liu, Gopikrishnan, Cizeau, Meyer, Peng and Stanley (1999) and ‘Scaling of the distribution of price fluctuations of individual companies’ by Vasiliki, Gopikrishnan, Amaral, Meyer and Stanley (1999). Both of these papers conclude that on a statistical level, market price behaviour follows an allometric law. Therefore, EMH is most definitely false. Conclusion We have analysed three fundamental theoretical and empirical problems with the EMH. We have suggested two modern approaches to better fitting the empirical data and what we know about human psychology and the functioning of biological systems. We conclude that the EMH fits the facts by accident, and is in fact false when considering a wider picture. (^4) For example, neurons reside in a state of chaotic randomness when not activated and move out of it into order when they fire (Stewart 1997).
Sharpe, W.F., (1970), Portfolio Theory and Capital Markets , McGraw‐Hill, New York. Stewart, I., (1997), Does God Play Dice? – The New Mathematics of Chaos 2 nd^ ed, Penguin Books, Great Britain. Vasiliki, P., Gopikrishnan, P., Amaral, L.A.N., Meyer, M. & Stanley, H.E. (1999), ‘Scaling of the distribution of price fluctuations of individual companies’, Physical Review E , vol. 60, pp. 6519 –