Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Market Segmentation Theory - UNCC, Study notes of Financial Market

Market segementation theory: A pedagogical model for explaining the terms structures of interest rates.

Typology: Study notes

2021/2022

Uploaded on 03/31/2022

palumi
palumi 🇺🇸

4.2

(14)

245 documents

1 / 26

Toggle sidebar

This page cannot be seen from the preview

Don't miss anything!

bg1
1
MARKET SEGMENTATION THEORY: A PEDAGOGICAL MODEL FOR
EXPLAINING THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES
R. Stafford Johnson, Xavier University
Richard A. Zuber, University of North Carolina at Charlotte
John M. Gandar, University of North Carolina at Charlotte
Four theories have evolved over the years to explain the term structure of interest
rates: Market Segmentation Theory (MST), Preferred Habitat Theory (PHT), Pure
Expectation Theory (PET), and the Liquidity Premium Theory (LPT). In explaining
term structure, many financial markets texts emphasize PET and LPT as the primary
theory in explaining the shape of yield curves. Since MST is based on fundamental
supply and demand factors, the de-emphasis of MST as a term structure explanation
means t hat such important factors as economic conditions and monetary and fiscal
policy, as well as the interrelation between different debt market segments and
sectors, are not being fully examined in many financial market texts. This paper
presents the MST in t erms of a basic supply and demand model. This model, in turn,
can be used to explain how important economic forces influence the term structure
of interest rates and also as a foundation for explaining the other three term
structures theories.
INTRODUCTION
Over the last three decades interest rates have often followed patterns of persistent
increases or persistent decreases with fluctuations around these trends. This is illustrated in
Figure 1 where the rates on Treasury bills are shown from 1970 to 2003. As shown, in the
1970s and early 1980s the U.S.’s inflation led to increasing interest rates during that period. This
period of increasing rates was particularly acute from the late 1970s through early 1980s when
the U.S. Federal Reserve changed the direction of monetary policy by raising discount rates,
increasing reserve requirements, and lowering monetary growth. This period of increasing rates
was followed by a period of declining rates from the early 1980s to the late 1980s, then a period
of gradually increasing rates for most of the 1990s, and finally a period of decreasing rates from
2000 through 2003. The different interest rates levels observed since the 1970s can be explained
by such factors as economic growth, monetary and fiscal policy, and inflation.
Insert Figure 1 Here
In addition to the observed fluctuations in interest rate levels, there have also been
observed spreads between the interest rates on bonds of different categories and terms to
maturity over this same period. In general, spreads can be explained by differences in each
bond’s characteristics: risk, liquidity, and taxability. Interest rate differences can also be
observed between similar bonds with different maturities. Figure 2 shows two yield curve plots
of the yields to maturity, YTM, on U.S. government bonds with different maturities for early
2002 and early 1981. The lower graph in Figure 2 shows a positively-sloped yield curve in early
pf3
pf4
pf5
pf8
pf9
pfa
pfd
pfe
pff
pf12
pf13
pf14
pf15
pf16
pf17
pf18
pf19
pf1a

Partial preview of the text

Download Market Segmentation Theory - UNCC and more Study notes Financial Market in PDF only on Docsity!

MARKET SEGMENTATION THEORY: A PEDAGOGICAL MODEL FOR

EXPLAINING THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

R. Stafford Johnson, Xavier University Richard A. Zuber, University of North Carolina at Charlotte John M. Gandar, University of North Carolina at Charlotte

Four theories have evolved over the years to explain the term structure of interest rates: Market Segmentation Theory (MST), Preferred Habitat Theory (PHT), Pure Expectation Theory (PET), and the Liquidity Premium Theory (LPT). In explaining term structure, many financial markets t exts emphasize PET and LPT as the primary theory in explaining the shape of yield curves. Since MST is based on fundamental supply and demand factors, the de-emphasis of MST as a term structure explanation means t hat such important factors as economic conditions and monetary and fiscal policy, as well as the interrelation between different debt market segments and sectors, are not being fully examined in many financial market texts. This paper presents the MST in t erms of a basic supply and demand model. This model, in turn, can be used to explain how important economic forces influence the term structure of interest rates and also as a foundation for explaining the other three term structures theories.

INTRODUCTION

Over the last three decades interest rates have often followed patterns of persistent increases or persistent decreases with fluctuations around these trends. This is illustrated in Figure 1 where the rates on Treasury bills are shown from 1970 to 2003. As shown, in the 1970s and early 1980s the U.S.’s inflation led to increasing interest rates during that period. This period of increasing rates was particularly acute from the late 1970s through early 1980s when the U.S. Federal Reserve changed the direction of monetary policy by raising discount rates, increasing reserve requirements, and lowering monetary growth. This period of increasing rates was followed by a period of declining rates from the early 1980s to the late 1980s, then a period of gradually increasing rates for most of the 1990s, and finally a period of decreasing rates from 2000 through 2003. The different interest rates levels observed since the 1970s can be explained by such factors as economic growth, monetary and fiscal policy, and inflation.

Insert Figure 1 Here

In addition to the observed fluctuations in interest rate levels, there have also been observed spreads between the interest rates on bonds of different categories and terms to maturity over this same period. In general, spreads can be explained by differences in each bond’s characteristics: risk, liquidity, and taxability. Interest rate differences can also be observed between similar bonds with different maturities. Figure 2 shows two yield curve plots of the yields to maturity, YTM, on U.S. government bonds with different maturities for early 2002 and early 1981. The lower graph in Figure 2 shows a positively-sloped yield curve in early

2002 and the upper graph shows a negatively sloped curve in early 1981. Understanding what determines both the overall level and term structure of interest rates is an important subject in financial economics. One of the best ways to understand how market forces determine interest rates is to use fundamental supply and demand analysis. Many financial markets texts examine the level of interest rates by explaining a supply and demand for loanable funds model. One excellent supply and demand exposition is presented by Mishkin and Eakins [2003]. Using such a model, they show how changes in the economy, future interest rate expectations, inflation expectations, risk, liquidity, and monetary and fiscal policy policies affect interest rates by shifting bond demand and supply curves.

Insert Figure 2 Here

With respect to the term structure of interest rates, four theories have evolved over the years to try to explain the shapes of yield curves: Market Segmentation Theory (MST), Preferred Habitat Theory (PHT), Pure Expectation Theory (PET), and the Liquidity Premium Theory (LPT). In explaining term structure, many financial markets texts, including Mishkin’s and Eakins’, emphasize PET and LPT as the primary theory in explaining the term structure. Since MST, though, is based on fundamental supply and demand factors, the de-emphasis of MST as a yield curve explanation means that such important factors as economic conditions and monetary and fiscal policy, as well as the interrelation between different debt market segments and sectors, are not being fully examined in many financial market texts. In general, each of the four theories by itself is usually not sufficient to explain the shape of a yield curve; rather, the full explanation underlying the term structure of interest rates depends on elements of all four theories. The purpose of this paper is to present the MST in terms of a basic supply and demand model based on the Mishkin and Eakins’ model used for explaining the level of interest rates. This model, in turn, can be used to explain how important economic forces influence not only the level, but also the term structure, of interest rates and also as a foundation for explaining the other three term structures theories. We begin by defining the basic supply and demand model used for explaining the level of interest rates. We then extend the model to explain the MST. Finally, given the MST, we explain the other theories of term structure as extensions of the basic MST supply and demand conditions.

INTEREST RATES LEVELS: SUPPLY AND DEMAND ANALYSIS

Bond Demand

The general level of interest rates can be explained in terms of a basic bond supply and demand model. In determining the supply and demand for bonds, let us treat different bonds as being alike and simply assume the bond in question is a one-period, zero-coupon bond paying a principal of F equal to 100 at maturity and priced at P 0 to yield a rate i.

securities and buy more consumption goods and consumer durables. A similar inverse relation also exists between bond demand and its relative risk. If bonds become riskier relative to other investments, we would expect a decrease in demand, and if they become less risky relative to other investments, we would expect an increase in demand. In terms of liquidity, if more investors trade the bond, making it more marketable or liquid, then we would expect the demand for the bond to increase at each price or interest rate. Finally, any change in government policy, such as a change in monetary or fiscal policy, that changes bond demand would shift the bond demand curve. For example, a Fed action of changing the discount rate they charge banks for borrowing or changing the amount of reserves banks are required to maintain in order to secure their deposits, would change the amount of loans banks are willing to offer. In this model, a change in the supply of loanable funds is equivalent to a change in the demand for bonds and would be reflected by a shift in the bond demand curve.

Bond Supply

In general, the quantity supplied of bonds by corporations, governments, and intermediaries, BS, depends on such factors as the bond’s price or interest rate, the state of the economy, government policy, and expected future inflation:

BS^ = f(i or P 0 , gdp, Government Policy, E(inflation))

        • or - +

The bond supply curve in Figure 3, BSBS^ is positively sloped. This reflects the fundamental assumption that corporations, governments, and financial intermediaries will sell more bonds the greater the bond’s price or equivalently the lower the interest rate. Thus, at point C issuers are shown to supply only $300B worth of the bond when P 0 is 92.5926 and i is 8%, while at point D bond supply is shown to be $500B when P 0 is 96.1538 and i is 4%. It should be noted that since selling or supplying a bond is equivalent to obtaining or demanding a loan, the bond supply cur ve in Figure 3 can also be identified as a demand for loanable funds curve. The bond supply curve will shift in response to changes in the state of the economy, government policy, and expected inflation. A priori, we would expect an increase in the supply for the bond at each price or interest rate when the economy is growing and a decrease in supply when the economy is in recession. When an economy is expanding, business demand for both short-term assets, such as inventories and accounts receivable, and long-term assets, such as plants and equipment, will increase. As a result, companies find themselves selling more bonds (demanding more loans) to finance the increases in their short-term and long-term capital formation. In contrast, in recessionary periods, there is less capital formation and fewer bonds being sold by corporations, governments, and intermediaries Thus, we would expect the bond supply curve to shift to the right in periods of economic growth and to the left in periods of economic decline. The bond supply can also change as a result of the federal government’s fiscal and monetary policy. If the federal government has a deficit, then the Treasury will be raising funds in the financial market by selling more Treasury securities. This would increase the supply of bonds at each price, shifting the supply curve to the right. In contrast, if there were a government surplus, the bond supply would decrease if the Treasury decided to use the surplus to buy up existing Treasury securities in order to reduce the government’s outstanding debt. In this case, the bond supply curve would shift to the left. In addition to Treasury financing, bond

supply is also affected by central bank policies. For example, in an expansionary open market operation (OMO), the central bank buys existing Treasury securities. If we limit the definition of bond supply to those bonds held by the public and not the central bank, then an expansionary OMO leads to a decrease in the supply of bonds and a leftward shift in the supply cur ve. In contrast, when the central bank is fighting inflation, it may try to slow the economy down by increasing interest rates through a contractionary OMO. Here the bank sells some of its holdings of Treasury securities, increasing the supply of bonds and shifting the supply curve to the right. Finally, if inflation is expected to be higher in the future, then expected borrowing cost will be higher in the future and more funds (inflated funds) will be needed to finance capital formation. As a result, corporations will find it advantageous to borrow more funds now. This would cause the bond supply to increase and the bond supply curve to shift to the right.

Market Equilibrium

Given the factors determining the supply and demand for bonds, the bond price or interest rate that ultimately prevails in the market is the one at which the quantity demanded of the bond equals the quantity supplied: BD^ = BS. The equilibrium rate, i* and price, P 0 , are graphically defined by the intersection of the supply and demand curves. In Figure 3, this occurs at P 0 * = 94.34 and i = 6% where the quantity demanded and supplied are both $400B. The equilibrium interest rate of 6% is the market-clearing interest rate and the equilibrium price of 94. is the market-clearing price. If the bond price were below this equilibrium price (or equivalently the interest rate were above the equilibrium rate), then investors would want more bonds than issuers were willing to sell. This excess demand would drive the price of the bonds up, decreasing the demand (movement down along the demand curve) and increasing the supply (movement along the supply curve) until the excess was eliminated. On the other hand, if the price on bonds were higher than its equilibrium (or interest rates lo wer that the equilibrium rate), then bondholders would want fewer bonds, while issuers would want to sell more bonds. This excess supply in the market would lead to lower prices and higher interest rates, increasing bond demand (movement along the bond demand curve) and reducing bond supply (movement along the supply curve) until the excess supply was eliminated. Thus, only at P 0 * and i*, where bond demand equals bond supply, is there an equilibrium where bondholders and suppliers do not want to change.

Comparative Analysis

The insights that one can gain from supply and demand analysis come from identifying the important factors that affect the positions of the demand and supply curves. Analytically, changes in these factors cause shifts in the demand or supply curves that, in turn, lead to new equilibrium bond price and interest rate levels. To illustrate, consider an OMO in which the central bank either purchases (expansionary OMO) or sells (contractionary OMO) Treasury securities. Such actions change not only the public's holdings of securities, but also the general level of interest rates in the economy. In addition to open market operations, we also noted that the central bank can also affect the level of interest rates by changing the discount rate it charges banks for borrowing and by reducing the amount of reserves banks are required to maintain to secure their deposits. One of the most dramatic monetary actions was undertaken by the U.S. Federal Reserve (Fed) in the late 1970s and early 1980s. Beginning in October of 1979 and extending through October 1982, the Fed

MST, the desire by investors and borrowers to avoid market risk leads to hedging practices that tend to segment the markets for bonds of different maturities.

MST in Terms of the Supply and Demand Model

One way to examine how market forces determine the shape of yield curves is to examine MST using our supply and demand analysis. Consider a simple world in which there are two types of corporate bonds -- long-term (BcLT ) and short-term (BcST) -- and two types of government Treasury bonds -- long-term (BT LT)) and short-term (BT ST)). Exhibit 1 shows the markets for each of the sectors and segments and the resulting yield curves for Treasury and corporate bonds. The supplies and demands for each sector and segment are based on the following assumptions:

  • The most important factors determining the demand for short-term bonds (both corporate and Treasury) are the bond’s own price or interest rate, government policy, liquidity, and risk. Short-term bond demand, BDST, is assumed to be inversely related to its price and directly related to its own rate (negatively sloped bond demand curves); government actions that affect the supply of loanable funds also can change bond demand (e.g., monetary policy changing bank reserve requirements).
  • The demand for the short-term bond in one sector is also assumed to be an inverse function of the short-term rate in the other sector, but not the long-term rate in either its sector or the other sector given the assumption of segmented markets. Thus, if the interest rate on the short-term Treasury security, iT ST, were to increase, investors would want more of the government bond and less of the short-term corporate bond. The increase in iT ST would therefore have an inverse effect on the demand for the short-term corporate, decreasing its demand and shifting its demand curve to the left. Conversely, an increase in the corporate short-term rate, icST, would lower the demand for the short-term Treasury security, shifting its demand curve to the left.
  • The most important factors determining the demand for long-term bonds (both corporate and Treasury) BDLT , are the bond’s own price or interest rate, government policy such as monetary actions (e.g., change in bank reserve requirements), liquidity, and risk. Demand is assumed to be inversely related to its price and directly related to its own rate (negatively sloped bond demand curves). In addition, the demand for the long-term bond in one sector, BDLT , is an inverse function of the long-term rate in the other sector, but not a function of the short-term rates given the market segmentation assumption.

BD f(i ,i ,risk,liquidity,government policy )

BD f(i ,i ,risk,liquidity,government policy) c ST

T LT

T ST

T ST

c ST

c ST =

BD f(i ,i ,risk,liquidity,government policy )

BD f(i , i ,risk,liquidity,government policy) c LT

T LT

T LT

T LT

c LT

c LT =

  • The supplies of short-term and long-term corporate bonds are directly related to their own price and inversely to their interest rate (positively sloped corporate bond supply curve) and directly related to general economic conditions, increasing in economic expansion and decreasing in recession.
  • The supplies of Treasury bonds depend only on government actions (monetary and fiscal policy), and not on the economic state or interest rates. This assumption says that the sale or purchase of Treasury securities by the central bank or the Treasury is a policy decision. The assumption that the supply of Treasury securities depends on government actions and not interest rates means that the bond supply curve is vertical.

Insert Exhibit 1 Here

In Exhibit 1, the two equilibrium rates for short-term and long-term corporate bonds are plotted against their corresponding maturities (simply denoted as S-T and L-T) to generate the yield curve for corporate bonds. Similarly, the equilibrium rates for short-term and long-term Treasury bonds are plotted against their corresponding maturities to generate the yield curve for Treasury bonds. These yield curves, in turn, capture a MST world in which interest rates for each segment are determined by the supply and demand for that bond, with the rates on bonds in the other maturity segments having no effect. In general, the positions and the shapes of the yield curves depend on the factors that determine supply and demand for short-term and long-term bonds. In this analysis, the state of the economy determines the positions of the supply curves; the rates on government securities determine the positions of the corporate bond demand curves, while the rates on corporate securities determine the positions of the Treasury bond demand curves; and depending on the type of policy, Treasury and central bank actions affect the Treasury bond supply curves and possible the bond demand curves. Cha nges in these factors will cause a change in the structure of interest rates that will be reflected by different shifts in the yield curves. Several cases of yield curve shifts are discussed below.

Case 1: Economic Recession

Suppose the economy moved from a period of economic growth into a recession. As noted, when an economy moves into a recession, business demand for short-term and long-term assets tends to decrease. As a result, many companies find themselves selling fewer short-term bonds, given that they plan to maintain smaller inventories and expect to have fewer accounts

BS f(i ,gdp )

BS f(i ,gdp) c LT

c LT

c ST

c ST =

BS f(government policy )

BS f(government policy) T LT

T ST =

total adjustment to the Treasury’s sale of short-term securities would occur through the increase in short-term corporate and Treasury rates. Moreover, given corporate and Treasury yield curves that are initially flat, as shown in Exhibit 3, the Treasury’s action causes the yield curves to become negatively sloped. By contrast, if the Treasury had financed the deficit with long-term securities, the impact would have been felt in the long-term bond market. In this case, the Treasury and corporate bond yield curves would have become positively slope.

Insert Exhibit 3 Here

In the case of a budget surplus (such as the brie f one that occurred in the U.S. in the late 1990s and early 2000), the yield curve could become negatively sloped if the Treasury used some of the surplus to buy up long-term Treasury securities as a policy to reduce the government’s debt. That is, the Treasury’s purchase of long-term securities would create an excess demand for long- term Treasury bonds, and by the substitution effect, excess demand for long-term corporate bonds, leading to higher price and lower rates on long-term securities.

Case 3: Ope n Market Operations

The yield curve can also be affected by the direction of monetary policy and how it is implemented. For example, if the central bank were engaged in an expansionary OMO in which it were buying short-term Treasury securities, there wo uld be a tendency for the yield curve to become positively sloped if the central bank were buying short-term securities, and a tendency for the yield curve to be become negatively sloped if it were to purchase long-term securities. On the other hand, in a contractionary OMO, there would be a tendency for the Treasury yield curve to become negatively sloped if the central bank were to sell some of its holdings of short-term bills and positively sloped if it were to sell some of its long-term security holdings. In addition to affecting the Treasury yield curve, open market operations also change the yield curve for corporate securities through a substitution effect. For example, an expansionary OMO in which the Fed purchases short-term Treasury securities would tend to cause the yield curve for corporate securities to become positively sloped. That is, as the rate on short-term Treasury securities decreases as a result of the OMO (short-term Treasury bond supply decreases, see Exhibit 4), the demand for short-term corporate bonds would increase (short-term corporate bond demand curve shifts right), causing higher prices and lower yields on the short-term corporate securities. Again, since the long-term market is assumed to be independent of short-term rates, the total adjustment to the Fed’s purchase of short-term securities would only occur in the short-term corporate and Treasury market and not in the long-term markets. If both the Treasury and corporate yield curves were initially flat, as shown in Exhibit 4, then the expansionary OMO would result in new positively sloped yield curves.

Insert Exhibit 4 Here

Summary of MST

The MST provides an economic foundation for explaining the shapes of yield curves in terms of fundamental supply and demand forces. As such, the model can be used to analyze the impacts of a number of economic activities on the term structure of interest rates. While the theory

can be used to explain a number of important economic forces, it has two shortcomings. First, by assuming independent markets, the MST does not recognize that it is possible that the rate of return on a bond in a particular maturity segment could increase to a level sufficient to induce investors to move out of their preferred segment and buy the bond with the higher rate in exchange for greater risk exposure. Secondly, MST does not take into account the role of expectations in determining the structure of interest rates. An investor with a two-year horizon period, for example, might prefer a series of one-year bonds to a two-year bond, if she expects relatively high yields on one-year bonds next year. If there are enough investors with such expectations, they could have an effect on the current demands for one- and two-year bonds. These limitations of MST are addressed in the other theories of term structures: the Preferred Habitat Theory, Pure Expectations Theory, and Liquidity Preference Theory.

OTHER TERM STRUCTURE THEORIES

Preferred Habitat Theory

MST assumes that investors and borrowers have preferred maturity segments or habitats determined by the maturities of their securities that they want to maintain. The Preferred Habitat Theory (PHT) posits that investors and borrowers may stray away from desired maturity segments if there are relatively better rates to compensate them. Furthermore, PHT asserts that investors and borrowers will be induced to forego their perfect hedges and shift out of their preferred maturity segments when supply and demand conditions in different maturity markets do not match. To illustrate PHT, consider an economic world in which, on the demand side, investors in corporate securities, on average, prefer short-term to long-term instruments, while on the supply side, corporations have a greater need to finance long-term assets than short-term, and therefore prefer to issue more long-term bonds than short-term. Combined, these relative preferences would cause an excess demand for short-term bonds and an excess supply for long-term claims and an equilibrium adjustment would have to occur. As summarized in Exhibit 5, the excess supply in the long-term market would force issuers to lower their bond prices, thus increasing bond yields and inducing some investors to change their short-term investment demands. In the short-term market, the excess demand would cause bond prices to increase and rates to fall, inducing some corporations to finance their long-term assets by selling short-term claims. Ultimately, equilibriums in both markets would be reached with long-term rates higher than short-term rates, a premium necessary to compensate investors and borrowers/issuers for the risk they've assumed.

Insert Exhibit 5 Here

As an explanation of term structure, the PHT would suggest that yield curves are positively sloped if investors, on the average, prefer short-term to long-term investments and borrowers/issuers prefer long to short. A priori, such preferences may be the case. That is, investors may prefer short-term investments given that longer maturity bonds tend to be more sensitive to interest rate changes or because there are more investors in the upper middle-age class (with shorter investment horizons) than in the young adult or middle-age class (with longer horizon periods). Borrowers also may have greater long-term than short-term financing needs and thus prefer to borrow long-term. Hence, one could argue that the yield curve is positively sloped because investors' and borrowers' preferences make the economy poorly hedged. Of course, the

Insert Exhibit 6 Here

If enough investors do this, an increase in the demand for one-year bonds and a decrease in the demand for two-year bonds would occur until the average annual rate on the two-year bond is equal to the equivalent annual rate from the series of one-year investments (or the one-year bond's rate is equal to the rate expected on the two-year bond held one year). In the example, if the price on a two-year bond fell such that it traded at a YTM of 9%, and the rate on a one-year bond stayed at 8%, then investors with two-year horizon dates would be indifferent between a two-year bond yielding a certain 9% and a series of one-year bonds yielding 10% and 8%, for an expected rate of 9%. Investors with one-year horizon dates would likewise be indifferent between a one-year bond yielding 8% and a two-year bond purchased at 9% and sold one year later at 10%, for an expected one-year rate of 8%. Thus in this case, the impact of the market's expectation of higher rates would be to push the longer-term rates up. In the above example, the yield curve is positively sloped, reflecting expectations of higher rates. By contrast, if the yield curve were currently flat at 10% and there was a market expectation that it would shift down to 8% next year, then the expectation of lower rates would cause the yield curve to become negatively sloped (see Exhibit 7). In this case, an investor with a two-year horizon date would prefer the two-year bond at 10% to a series of one-year bonds yielding an expected rate of only 9% (E(R) = [(1.10)(1.08)]1/2^ -1 = .09); an investor with a one-year horizon would also prefer buying a two-year bond that has an expected rate of return of 12% (P 2 =100/(1.10)^2 = 82.6446, E(P 11 ) = 100/1.08 = 92.5926, E(R ) = [92.5926-82.6446]/82.6446 = .12) to the one-year bond that yields only 10%. In markets for both one-year and two-year bonds, the expectations of lower rates would cause the demand and price of the two-year bond to increase, lowering its rate, and the demand and price for the one-year bond to decrease, increasing its rate. These adjustments would continue until the rate on the two-year bond equaled the average rate from the series of one-year investments, or until the rate on the one-year bond equaled the expected rate from holding a two- year bond one year. In this case, if one-year rates stayed at 8%, then the demand for the two-year bond would increase until it was priced to yield 9% - the expected rate from the series: [(1.10)(1.08)]1/2^ -1 = .09 (see Exhibit 7).

Insert Exhibit 7 Here

It should be noted that PET intuitively captures what should be considered as normal market behavior. That is, whether or not the market is risk neutral, has perfect expectations, or bonds are perfect substitutes, investors, as well as borrowers/issuers do factor in expectations. For example, if long-term rates were expected to be higher in the future (based perhaps on the expectation of greater economic growth), long-term investors (e.g., life insurance company, pension fund, etc.) would not want to purchase long-term bonds now, given that next period they would be expecting higher yields and lower prices on such bonds (they also would be exposed to possible capital losses if they did buy such bonds and were forced to liquidate them next year). Instead, such investors would invest in short-term securities now, reinvesting later at the expected higher long- term rates. In contrast, borrowers/issuers wishing to borrow long-term would want to sell long-term bonds now instead of later at possibly higher rates. Combined, the decrease in demand for long- term bonds by investors and the increase in the supply of long-term bonds by borrowers would serve to lower long-term bond prices and increase yields, leading to a positively-sloped yield curve.

Thus, a salient feature of PET is that it incorporates expectations as an important variable in explaining the structure of interest rates.

Liquidity Premium Theory

The Liquidity Premium Theory (LPT), also referred to as the Risk Premium Theory (RPT), posits that there is a liquidity premium for long-term bonds over short-term bonds. According to LPT, if investors are risk averse, then they would require some additional return (liquidity premium) in order to hold long-term bonds instead of short-term ones. Thus, if the yield curve were initially flat, but had no risk premium factored in to compensate investors for the additional volatility they assumed from buying long-term bonds, then the demand for long-term bonds would decrease and their rates increase until risk-averse investors were compensated. In this case, the yield curve would become positively sloped

SUMMARY OF TERM STRUCTURE THEORIES

As we noted earlier, the structure of interest rates cannot be explained in terms of any one theory; rather, it is best explained by a combination of theories. Of the four theories, the two major ones are MST and PET. MST is important because it establishes how the fundamental market forces governing the supply and demand for assets determines interest rates. PET, in turn, extends MST to show how expectations impact the structure of interest rates. PHT, by explaining how markets will adjust if the economy is poorly hedged, and LPT, by including a liquidity premium for longer-term bonds, both represent necessary extensions of MST and PET. Together, the four theories help us to understand how supply and demand, economic conditions, government deficits and surpluses, monetary policy, hedging, maturity preferences, and expectations all affect the bond market in general and the structure of rates in particular.

REFERENCES

Buser, S. A., and P. J. Hess. “Empirical Determinants of the Relative Yields on Taxable and Tax Exempt Securities.” Journal of Financial Economics 17 (1986): 335-355.

Campbell, J. Y. “A Defense of Traditional Hypotheses about the Term Structure of Interest Rates.” Journal of Finance 41 (1986): 183-93.

Campbell, T. “On the Extent of Segmentation in the Municipal Securities Market.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 12 (1980): 71-83.

Cox, J. C., J. Ingersoll, and S. Ross. “A Re-examination of Traditional Hypotheses about the Term Structure of Interest Rates.” Journal of Finance 36 (1981): 769-799.

Cox, J. C., J. Ingersoll, and S. Ross. “A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates.” Econometrica 53 (1985): 385-407.

Culbertson, J. M.. “The Term Structure of Interest Rates.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 71 (1957): 489-504.

Figure 1 Treasury Bill Rates, 1970-

Years

T-bill Rates

Figure 2 Yield Curve for U.S. Government Bonds

Years to Maturity

Rates (%)

January, 1981 January, 2001

Figure 4: Comparative Equilibrium Analysis Impact of a Contractionary Monetary Policy

Impact of a Contractionary Monetary Policy

  • Contractionary open market operation: Central bank sells bonds, increasing the bond supply and shifting the bond supply curve to the right.
  • An increase in the reserve requirement and an increase in the discount rate charged on bank loans by the central bank decreases the supply of loanable funds, shifting the bond demand curve to left.
  • Impact: Interest Rates Increase

Quantityof Bonds

(P )

BondPrice ↑ (^) (i )

InterestRate ↓

B 1 D

S B 1

P 0 0 i

0

0

B 1 S

B^ S 2

S B 2

B^ D 2

D B 1 B^ D 2

P 1 i 1

Exhibit 1: MST Model Market Equilibrium for Short-Term and Long -Term Corporate and Treasury Bonds

Corporate Bond Market

  • Short-Term Bonds

Quantity ofShort−TermCorporate Bonds

(P )

BondPrice ↑ (^) (i)

InterestRate ↓

B^ D

B^ S

  • icST*

0

0

B^ S

B^ D

P^ c 0

BD cST =f(icST,iSTT,risk,liquidity,governmentpolicy ) BS cST =f(icST,gdp )

( iTST* )

Corporate Bond Market

  • Long-Term Bonds

Quantity o fLong−TermCorporate Bonds

(P )

BondPrice ↑ (^) (i)

InterestRate ↓

B^ D

B^ S

  • (^) icLT*

0

0

B^ S

B^ D

P^ c 0

BS cLT =f(icLT,gdp )

BD cLT =f(icLT,iTLT,risk,liquidity,governmentpolicy )

(i TLT* )

Corporate Bond

  • Yield Curve

Maturity

InterestRate i

icLT* •

0

icST * •

ST L T

Treasury Bond Market

  • Short-Term Bonds

Quantity ofShort−TermTreasury Bonds

(P )

BondPrice ↑ (^) (i) InterestRate ↓

B^ D

B^ S

iTST^ *

0

0

B^ D

P 0 T

BD TST =f(iTL T,icST,risk,liquidity,governmentpolicy ) BS TST =f(governmentpolicy )

(i cST* )

Treasury Bond Market

  • Long-Term Bonds

Quantity ofLong−TermTreasury Bonds

(P )

BondPrice ↑ (^) (i) InterestRate ↓

B^ D

B^ S

  • iTLT*

0

0

B^ D

P 0 T

BD TLT =f(iTLT,icLT,risk,liquidity,governmentpolicy ) BSTLT =f(governmentpolicy )

(i cLT* )

Treasury Bond

  • Yield Curve

Maturity

InterestRate i

iTLT* •

0

iTST * •

ST LT