Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Solution for Microeconomics, Exercises of Economics

Solution of Microeconomics by Nelson

Typology: Exercises

2019/2020

Uploaded on 08/11/2020

frozen-spring
frozen-spring 🇧🇩

2 documents

1 / 8

Toggle sidebar

This page cannot be seen from the preview

Don't miss anything!

bg1
Solution Manual for Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles
and Extensions 10th Edition Chapters 2 19 by Nicholson
Complete downloadable file at:
https://testbanku.eu/Solution-Manual-for-Microeconomic-Theory-
Basic-Principles-and-Extensions-10th-Edition-Chapters-2-19-by-
Nicholson
The problems in this chapter are primarily mathematical. They are intended to give students
some practice with the concepts introduced in Chapter 2, but the problems in themselves offer
few economic insights. Consequently, no commentary is provided. Results from some of the
analytical problems are used in later chapters, however, and in those cases the student will be
directed to here.
Solutions
2.1 U (x, y) = 4x2 + 3y2
a.
6y =
y
U
,8x =
x
U
b. 8, 12
c. dU =
dy6y + dx 8x =dy
y
U
+ dx
x
U
d.
0 =dy y 6 +dx x 8 0 = dU for
dx
dy
3y
4x
=
6y
8x
=
dx
dy
e.
x = 1, y = 2 U = 4 1 + 3 4 = 16
f.
2/3 =
3(2)
4(1)
=
dx
dy
g. U = 16 contour line is an ellipse centered at the origin. With equation
2 2
4 3 16x y
, slope of the line at (x, y) is
3y
4x
=
dx
dy
.
2.2 a. Profits are given by
10 =
q
40 + 4q =
dq
d
*
100 = 100 40(10) +
)
2(10 =
2
*
b.
4 =
dq
d
2
2
so profits are maximized
c.
dR
MR = = 70 2q
dq
dC
MC = = 2q + 30
dq
pf3
pf4
pf5
pf8

Partial preview of the text

Download Solution for Microeconomics and more Exercises Economics in PDF only on Docsity!

Solution Manual for Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles

and Extensions 10th Edition Chapters 2 19 by Nicholson

Complete downloadable file at:

https://testbanku.eu/Solution-Manual-for-Microeconomic-Theory-

Basic-Principles-and-Extensions-10th-Edition-Chapters-2-19-by-

Nicholson

The problems in this chapter are primarily mathematical. They are intended to give students

some practice with the concepts introduced in Chapter 2, but the problems in themselves offer

few economic insights. Consequently, no commentary is provided. Results from some of the

analytical problems are used in later chapters, however, and in those cases the student will be

directed to here.

Solutions

2.1 U (x, y) = 4x

2

  • 3y

2

a.

=6y

y

U

=8x ,

x

U

b. 8, 12

c. dU =

dy=8x dx+6y dy

y

U

dx +

x

U

d.

fordU= 08 xdx+ 6 ydy= 0

dx

dy

3y

4x

=

6y

8x

=

dx

dy  

e.

x = 1, y = 2 U = 4 1+ 3 4 = 16

f.

= 2/

3(2)

4(1)

=

dx

dy

g. U = 16 contour line is an ellipse centered at the origin. With equation

2 2

4 x  3 y  16 , slope of the line at ( x, y ) is

3y

4x

=

dx

dy

.

2.2 a. Profits are given by

2

  RC  2 q  40 q  100

= 4q+ 40 q= 10

dq

d

+40(10) 100 = 100 )

= 2(

2

 

b.

= 4

dq

d

2

2

so profits are maximized

c.

dR

MR = = 70 2q

dq

dC

MC = = 2q + 30

dq

so q * = 10 obeys MR = MC = 50.

2.3 Substitution:

2

y   1 x so fxyxx

= 1 2x= 0

x

f

x = 0.5 , y = 0.5, f = 0.

Note:

f 2 0

. This is a local and global maximum.

Lagrangian Method:

£  xy  (1  xy )

= y = 0

x

= x = 0

y

so, x = y.

using the constraint gives

xy 0.5, xy 0.

2.4 Setting up the Lagrangian:

£  xy  (0.25  xy ) .

y

x

x

y

So, x = y. Using the constraint gives

2

xyx 0.25, xy 0..

2.5 a.

2

f t ( )  0.5 gt  40 t

df

= g t + 40 = 0 t

dt g

b. Substituting for t* ,

  • 2

f t ( )  0.5 (40 g g )  40(40 g )  800 g .

2

f t

g

g

c.

2

f 1

t

g 2

depends on g because t

depends on g.

so

  • 2 2

2

f 800

= t

g g g

d.

a reduction of .08. Notice that

2 2

 800 g 800 32  0.8so a 0.1 increase in g could be predicted to

reduce height by 0.08 from the envelope theorem.

98 Fixed Costs

98 0

14 ) 0

2

14

( ) 15 * 14 (

2

 

 

     

C

C

pq TC q C

c. If p=20, q = 19. Following the same steps as in b., and using C=98, we get

19 98 ) 82. 5

2

19

( ) 20 * 19 (

2

 pqTCq     

So, profits increase by 82.

d. Assuming profit maximization, we have p = MC(q)

98

2

( 1 )

( 1 ) 98

2

( 1 )

98 ) ( 1 )

2

(

1 1

2 2 2

  

      

    

p

p

p

q p p

q

pq

p q q p

e. i. Using the above equation, π(20) - π(15) = 82.

ii.

  1. 5

2

( 20 ) ( 15 ) ( 1 )

20

15

2

20

15

     

p

p

  p dp

The 2 approaches above demonstrate the envelope theorem. In the first case,

we optimize q first and then substitute it into the profit function. In the second

case, we directly vary the parameter (i.e., p ) and essentially move along the

firm’s supply curve.

Analytical Problems

2.9 Concave and Quasiconcave Functions

The proof is most easily accomplished through the use of the matrix algebra of

quadratic forms. See, for example, Mas Colell et al., pp. 937-939. Intuitively,

because concave functions lie below any tangent plane, their level curves must

also be convex. But the converse is not true. Quasi-concave functions may

exhibit “increasing returns to scale”; even though their level curves are convex,

they may rise above the tangent plane when all variables are increased together.

A counter example would be the Cobb-Douglas function which is always quasi-

concave, but convex when α+β > 1.

2.10 The Cobb-Douglas Function

a.

1

1

1 2

f > 0. x x

 

2

1

1 2

f > 0. x x

 

11

2

1 1

f ( 1) < 0. x x

 

22

2

1 2

f ( 1) < 0.

x x

 

 

12 21

1 1

1 2

f f > 0.

x x

 

 

Clearly, all the terms in Equation 2.114 are negative.

b. If x x

y =c=

2

1

 

c x

x

/

1

1/

2

   

since α, β > 0, x 2

is a convex function of x 1

c. Using equation 2.98,

x x x x

f f f = ( 1)( )( 1)

2 2

2

2 2

1

2 2 2 2

2

2 2

1

2

22 12

   

   

   

 

   

11

x x

2 2

2

2 2

1

 

 

    which is negative for α + β > 1.

2.11 The Power Function

a. Since

y 0, y 0

, the function is concave.

b. Because

11 22

f , f  0 , and

12 21

ff  0 , Equation 2.98 is satisfied and the

function is concave. Because

1 2

f , f  0 Equation 2.114 is also satisfied so

the function is quasi-concave.

c. y is quasi-concave as is

y

. But

y

is not concave for

. This can

be shown most easily by

1 2 1 2 1 2

f (2 x , 2 x ) [(2 x ) (2 x ) ] 2 f ( x , x )

   

2.12 Taylor Approximations

a. From Equation 2.85, a function in one variable is concave if

f ' '( x ) 0

Using the quadratic Taylor to approximate

f ( x )

near a point a:

2

f ( x ) f ( a ) f '( a )( xa ) 0. 5 f ''( a )( xa )

f ( a ) f '( a )( xa )

(because

( ) 0 ( ) 0

2

  

 f a and x a )

The RHS above is the equation of the line tangent to the point a and so,

we have shown that any concave function must lie on or below the tangent

to the function at that point.

b. From Equation 2.98, a function in 2 variables is concave if

2

11 22 12

f ff

and we also know that due to the concavity of the function,

2

12 1 2 22 2

2

11 1

2

d yf dxf dxdxf dx

So, 0.5(

2

12 1 2 22 2

2

11 1

f dx  2 f dxdxf dx )  0.

This is the third term of the quadratic Taylor expansion where

dxxa , dyyb

.

Thus, we have

( , ) ( , ) ( , )( ) ( , )( )

1 2

f x yf abf ab xaf ab yb

t

E x

t

Since x

t t

E x

t

P x t F t t

1 ( )

1 ,

( ) 1

1

( ) 1 ( )

2

2

2

 

    

Thus, Markov’s inequality holds.

f. 1.   1

9

1

3

( )

2

1

3

2

1

2

  

  

dx x

x

f x dx

4

5

12

16 1

12

1

3

( ) ( )

2

1

4

2

1

3

   

  

dx x

x

Ex xf x dx

9

1

9

1

3

( 1 0 )

0

1

3

0

1

2

     

dx x

x

P x

2

2

    x

x

x

P A

P xand A

f x A

2

3

32

3

8

3

( ) ( )

2

0

4

2

0

3

   

 

dx x

x

E xA xf xA dx

  1. Eliminating the lowest values for x should increase the expected

value of the remaining values.

2.14 More on Variances and Covariances

a.

2 2

2 2 2 2

2 2 2

( ) ( ( ))

( ) 2 ( ( )) (( ( )) ) ( ) 2 ( ( ) ( )) ( ( ))

( ) [( ( )) ] ( 2 ( ) ( ( )) )

Ex E x

Ex ExE x E Ex Ex E xEx E x

Var x E x Ex Ex xE x E x

 

     

    

b.

( ) ( ) ( )

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

[ ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )]

( , ) [( ( ))( ( ))]

E xy E x E y

E xy E x E y E y E x E xE y

E xy xE y yE x E xE y

Cov x y E x E x y E y

 

   

   

  

c.

2 2

Var ( axby ) E [( axby ) ]( E ( axby )) (From part a.)

( ) ( ) 2 ( , )

( ) 2 ( ) ( ) ( ( )) 2 ( ) ( ) ( ( ))

( 2 ) ( ( ) ( ))

2 2

2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2

2 2 2 2 2

aVar x bVar y abCov x y

a E x abExy b Ey a Ex abEx E y b E y

Ea x axby b y aEx bE y

  

    

    

(From results of parts a. and b.)

d.

E (. 5 x . 5 y ). 5 E ( x ). 5 E ( y ) E ( x )

Remember that if 2 random variables x and y are independent, then

Cov(x, y) = 0

. 5 ( )

(. 5. 5 ). 25 ( ). 25 ( ) 0

Var x

Var x y Var x Var y

   

If x and y characterize 2 different assets with the properties

E ( x ) E ( y ),var( x )var( y ) we have shown that the variance of a

diversified portfolio is only half as large as for a portfolio invested in only

one of the assets.