









Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Prepare for your exams
Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points to download
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Community
Ask the community for help and clear up your study doubts
Discover the best universities in your country according to Docsity users
Free resources
Download our free guides on studying techniques, anxiety management strategies, and thesis advice from Docsity tutors
The research and publications of Steven A. Bank, a professor of business law at a university in the US. He specializes in tax and business law and has published articles and books on business taxation, tax policy, and business and tax history. The document also briefly touches on the history of blockholder control in the UK and the US in the early 20th century.
Typology: Lecture notes
1 / 17
This page cannot be seen from the preview
Don't miss anything!
UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW Scholarly Perspectives [ 3 ]
Steven Bank teaches in the area of tax and business_._ His research generally explores the taxation of business entities through the lens of legal and business history. Professor Bank was the faculty director of UCLA School of Law’s Program in Business Law & Policy from 2005 to 2007.
Professor Bank has published numerous articles and chapters in the fields of business taxation, tax policy, and business and tax history, and has co-authored or edited several books, including From Sword to Shield: The Transformation of the Corporate Income Tax, 1861 to Present (Oxford University Press, 2010), War and Taxes (Urban Institute Press, 2008), Taxation of Business Enterprises (West, 2012) and Business Tax Stories (Foundation Press, 2005). His articles have been selected for the Stanford/Yale Junior Faculty Forum and the John Minor Wisdom Award for Academic Excellence in Legal Scholarship. He has also been a Herbert Smith visitor at the University of Cambridge and lectured at the United Kingdom’s Inland Revenue on the development of the U.S. and British corporate income taxes.
Paul Hastings Professor of Business Law Faculty Director, Lowell Milken Institute for Business Law and Policy
[ 4 ] Scholarly Perspectives UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW
[ 6 ] Scholarly Perspectives UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW
location of corporate power, in turn, contributed to the divergence of corporate income tax schemes. The reason is that the corporation itself was simply perceived differently in the two countries during the first half of the twentieth century when the income tax systems were still developing. Power in the large British public corporation was primarily located at the shareholder level, thus leading to a shareholder-focused corporate tax, while power in the large American public corporation was primarily located at the entity level, thus leading to an entity- focused corporate tax. These differences were then hard-wired into the respective national consciences and continued to influence corporate tax reform in ensuing years.
This difference in the locus of power in British and American corporations not only affected decisions about the appropriate dividend policy, but it may have affected views on the appropriate role of corporate taxation in regulating corporate power and in reaching corporate wealth. To the extent that ownership separated from control much later in the U.K. than in the U.S., U.K. policymakers may have conceived of a family controlled corporation when they contemplated the taxation of the corporation. This necessarily would have suggested a more aggregate conception of the corporation, pointing toward an integrated approach to the taxation of corporate income. Conversely, if in the U.S., the separation of ownership and control occurred much earlier, the rise of the manager-controlled enterprise may have made it easier to conceive of a classical system of corporate taxation in which the corporation was taxed separately on its earnings. Moreover, variations in tax treatment could occur at various points and on individual provisions in response to specific contingencies or because of shifts in the nature of corporate ownership and governance. Nevertheless, the justifications for such variations were often framed in the historical rhetoric. Thus, the adoption of an American-style classical corporate income tax in the U.K. between 1965 and 1973 was justified as an aid to stemming the tide of excessive dividends paid to wealthy shareholders, while the adoption of an undistributed profits tax in the U.S. between 1936 and 1939 was justified as a means of constraining abusive managers.
T
he differing contemporary descriptions of the corporation and the differences that developed in the fundamental nature of the respective corporate tax systems during the early twentieth century are connected. Given this, it is valuable to examine the divergence in the development of the corporation itself that occurred between the turn-of-the-century and the onset of World War II. This includes legal and practical differences in the position of shareholders and the locus of power as a result of the varying degree to which ownership separated from control in the two countries over this period.
Although the U.S. and the U.K. were more or less on parallel tracks in the growth and dispersion of their shareholder populations in the early twentieth century, the
I. THE DIVERGENCE IN THE NATURE OF THE CORPORATION
A. Familial Capitalism and the Presence of Blockholders
UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW Scholarly Perspectives [ 7 ]
countries diverged as to the extent of blockholder control. This had two dimensions. First, families maintained controlling stakes in British public corporations, at least in the industrial and manufacturing sectors, at a relatively high rate. Second, American corporations more quickly developed a management structure that ceded control to individuals who were not directly associated with or controlled by the shareholders. The combination meant that even amidst the growth in public corporations and the expansion of stock ownership in both countries, different patterns emerged. While the U.S. was moving closer to the outsider/arm’s-length structure of corporate governance, the U.K. continued to adhere to the insider/control-oriented model.
In both the U.K. and the U.S., the founding families of newly-public corporations often maintained control of their early twentieth century corporations by retaining ownership of a block of stock sufficient to affect voting. In the U.K., for instance, Imperial Tobacco continued to be dominated by the Wills family even after a 1901 merger of seventeen U.K. tobacco companies and an ensuing public offering in 1902 designed to finance the merger. At the time, the Wills family owned sixty-eight percent of the resulting company’s ordinary shares and it still held fifty-five percent in 1911 after the death of William Henry Wills, the founding chairman of Imperial.^1 One commentator later described Imperial as a “glorified family firm.” 2 This phenomenon was true even for very large firms with widely-dispersed shareholders. Lever Brothers, a British soap manufacturer and the forerunner of the modern conglomerate Unilever, had 187,000 shareholders but “remained firmly under the thumb” of its founder, William Lever, until his death in 1925, through the family’s control over the voting stock and the management structure. 3 To avoid diluting family control, the company only issued debentures and non-voting preferred stock and other stock with limited or no voting rights in connection with their aggressive acquisition campaigns. 4
The British companies were not unique in this regard in the early twentieth century. In the U.S., large companies such as Ford Motor Company, the Mellon family’s Gulf Petroleum and Aluminum Company of America, and the Duke family’s American Tobacco Company were all heavily dominated by family ownership and control. 5 According to studies of corporations in the first several decades of the twentieth century, a similar percentage of families, or other shareholder groups, maintained control in the U.S. as in the U.K. In Berle and Means’ study, fifty-five percent of the largest 200 American corporations were controlled by minority blockholders such as families as of 1929. 6 Likewise, Leslie Hannah found that fifty-five percent of the largest 200 British corporations had family members on the board of directors in 1919, with that percentage rising to seventy by 1930. 7
The difference between the U.S. and the U.K. was not in the presence of family control in the early 1900s, but rather in the extent to which it continued through
I. Blockholders
UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW Scholarly Perspectives [ 9 ]
Between 1880 and 1930, the small, privately held, family-controlled U.S. business appeared to gradually give way to the large, publicly traded, manager-controlled corporation.^18 According to Alfred Chandler, such a transformation primarily occurred before World War I, with U.S. companies developing independent and sophisticated management structures quite distinct from their shareholders.^19 This phenomenon was repeatedly emphasized by contemporary observers. F. Edson White, the president of a meatpacking firm Armour and Company, reported in a 1924 interview that “[b]ig business is rapidly becoming decentralized in ownership
Adolf Berle and Gardiner Means offered empirical data to buttress these contemporary observations of the transformation to a manager-led corporation. In their famous 1932 study, 23 Berle and Means documented that a substantial majority of the 200 largest corporations in 1930 were controlled by management rather than by an individual or family.^24 They wrote “[w]e have reached a condition in which the individual interest of the shareholder is definitely subservient to the will of a controlling group of managers even though the capital is made up of the aggregated contributions of perhaps many thousands of individuals.”^25 Although their conclusion was not as clearly supported by their data as they asserted, 26 other studies soon followed to confirm that many of the largest corporations in the U.S. were indeed controlled by managers.
In the U.K., this transformation to a manager-controlled corporation appeared to take place much later than in the U.S. John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge, in their history of the company, described this divergence:
British entrepreneurs clung to the personal approach to management long after their American cousins had embraced professionalism. As late as the Second World War, a remarkable number of British firms were managed by members of the founding families. These founders kept the big decisions firmly within the company, only calling on the help of professional managers in extremis. Family-run firms had no need for the detailed organizational charts and manuals that had become commonplace in large American companies. They relied instead on personal relations and family traditions.^27
For example, a study by Phillip Sargant Florence of eighty-two of the largest industrial and commercial firms in Britain as of 1936 found that the vast majority had a dominant owner.^28 Similarly, in a recent study of fifty-five listed U.K. firms as
[ 10 ] Scholarly Perspectives UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW
of 1950 by Julian Franks, Colin Mayer, and Stefano Rossi, the authors reported that the largest ten shareholders held an average of almost forty-nine percent of the shares.^29 The real transition appeared to occur during the 1960s. In 1961, Anthony Sampson analyzed twenty-three of the largest U.K. companies by asset value and concluded that among these firms “there is still often a family or an individual with a dominating influence on the board.” 30 A decade later, in 1971, Sampson concluded that “the big corporations are left, like perpetual clocks, to run themselves; and the effective power resides not with the shareholders but with the boards of directors.”^31
Even if the formal separation of ownership and control had occurred at roughly the same time in the two countries, shareholders maintained a degree of influence over corporate governance in British companies that did not exist in the U.S. This may have had long-standing roots. Lorraine Talbot attributes the British conception of shareholders to the survival of legal protections that emerged during the dominance of quasi-partnership companies in the post-Bubble Act era, noting that even after shares in widely-dispersed companies were reconceptualized as personal property rather than taking on the character of the firm’s assets, “[s]hareholders were still conceived as owners with the entitlement of owners, which seems to be more extensive than mere ownership of shares.” 32 Talbot even suggests that this persists to the modern day, although this may be an overstatement: “In the United Kingdom, shareholders continue to be considered the owners of companies and the proper recipients of corporate activity, regardless of the level of share dispersal.” 33
One area where the difference in shareholder rights was particularly stark, at least on the face of it, was in dividend policy. From the middle of the nineteenth century, British shareholders of most companies were accorded the right to vote on the Board’s recommendation to declare a dividend. This right was incorporated in Table A of the U.K.’s Company Acts, which set forth a number of default rules that companies could adopt in constructing their charters.^34 According to paragraph 72 of Table A, “[t]he Directors may, with the Sanction of the Company in General Meeting, declare a Dividend to be paid to the Members in proportion to their shares.”^35 For many companies, the articles of association borrowed liberally from Table A, including the provision for shareholder vote on dividends. 36 According to Professor Colleen Dunlavy’s forthcoming database on corporate charters, which describes dividend and other provisions in a series of U.K. charters adopted between 1845 and 1865, two-thirds of the charters included provisions requiring shareholder approval for declaration of a dividend. 37 Although shareholders generally could not vote to change the amount of a Board’s recommended dividend and they could not initiate a dividend, 38 they could veto a dividend recommendation.
By contrast, U.S. shareholders have never held any power, even in the form of a veto right, over the dividend decision. The board of directors had the sole discretion to determine dividend policy. There were early instances in which the dividend
B. Corporate Governance
[ 12 ] Scholarly Perspectives UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW
“preferring to hold annual general meetings far from where shareholders lived or worked.”^47 In 1947, the Investors’ League cited the examples of a paper company that held its annual meeting at an abandoned paper mill that could only be reached by a special train and a meeting of the American Can Company in an upstate New York town that was not accessible by rail at all. 48 Even where meetings were held in cities accessible to most shareholders, they were held on the same day as meetings of other corporations in different cities, effectively preventing shareholders from attending meetings of more than one of the corporations in which it held shares. 49
Part of the explanation for this difference in approach to annual and special meetings was structural differences in the corporate law governing U.K. and U.S. companies. As Janette Rutterford has explained, the federal system in the U.S. permitted businesses to be headquartered in one state, but incorporated in an entirely different and often far-off state. Because the choice to incorporate in a state was often a product of a competition among states to offer the most favorable laws for business and its managers, this meant that the protections for shareholders and the disclosure requirements were often quite minimal. The U.S. did not provide uniform disclosure requirements until the 1930s with the creation of the Securities Exchange Commission. The difference between the business home and legal home of a corporation also meant that annual meetings held near the registered office were more ceremonial than substantive, since they could be located quite a distance from any natural shareholding population surrounding the actual business operation of the company.^50 By contrast, in the U.K., with all English and Welsh companies filing documents and information to the Registrar of Companies in London starting in 1900, there was no advantage to locate far from a company’s base of operations and its natural shareholder and employee constituency. 51 Disclosure was also more complete in the early twentieth century U.K. firm, with the Companies Act of 1900 even requiring the publication of shareholder lists.^52 In a legal environment in which disclosure was required more broadly, the annual meeting might have the chance of actually being informative rather than merely ceremonial.
Even apart from the logistical obstacles to attending annual meetings in the U.S., the average shareholder had little incentive to attend. Frequently, their questions were ignored if there was even time reserved for questions at all.^53 Corporate management was highly suspicious of shareholder motives in this context. One railroad chief executive officer, James J. Hill of the Great Northern Railroad, reportedly testified before the Pujo Committee in 1913 that in thirty years “no stockholder so far as he could remember had attended the meetings... unless he wanted to make trouble.”^54 John Broderick, in his book, A Small Stockholder , offered a colorful explanation for why the lack of any chance to influence the corporation led people to ignore annual meetings:
UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW Scholarly Perspectives [ 13 ]
What I am trying to calculate at the moment is the measure of interest that there is for me in any meeting of corporation stockholders which I am entitled to attend. In fact, while I am usually at ease in the presence of death in any form, if I were obligated to choose between hying to one of these corporate powwows, with its arid ceremonial, and going to a funeral, with its moving solemnity, there is no doubt that I would pick the funeral. At a friend’s obsequies one may at least speak a consoling word to the widow, if he knows how, and possibly serve as a pallbearer. 55
As a result, John Sears of the Corporation Trust Company noted that “[i]t has become... customary for stockholders’ meetings to be... devoid of personal attendance or participation in discussions.” 56
There was reportedly a very different scene at annual meetings of British corporations, where annual meeting attendance had a long tradition. Indeed, while there were some instances of non-attendance and proxy voting, it “should not be assumed that it was very widespread.”^57 A Royal Commission in 1886 found that “the directors are as a rule well looked after, meetings are frequent: generally they are held quarterly.”^58 This general practice continued in the twentieth century, although by then proxy voting had gained a foothold, leading to dire predictions of the decline of the importance of the meeting. 59 Such predictions did not prove true. Sears noted that “[i]n contrast with our American experience we hear frequent reference to the large attendance, real discussions, and results secured at stockholders’ meetings in England.” 60 The Wall Street Journal marveled that:
Stockholders’ meetings are held in London in a hall that accommodates two thousand people and it is frequently crowded. There is always a good attendance. The directors sit on the platform, with their chairman, and answer questions after the report has been read. The questions are usually shrewd and searching, and woe betide the director who tries to evade them. Such meetings are well reported in the newspapers, especially if the company is a prominent one. The result of this publicity is that the will of the stockholder tends to prevail. 61
This does not mean, of course, that shareholders in the U.K. agreed with their American counterparts in concluding that British shareholder meetings were productive and useful or that shareholders in the U.S. were ineffective in imposing their will on directors. The popularity and significance of the shareholder meeting does suggest why a British shareholder might feel more involved in the governance of the corporation than a comparable American shareholder.
Company law provided further encouragement to the annual meeting function of British corporations. Shareholders in the U.K. were afforded some legal
UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW Scholarly Perspectives [ 15 ]
to continue to thrive, in the U.K. they were also worried about shareholder expropriation while in the U.S. they were worried about managerial expropriation. Since laws and attitudes linger long after the facts supporting them have dissipated, tax policy continued to be animated by these concerns at least through the post- World War II period, and in some cases through to the current day.
[ 16 ] Scholarly Perspectives UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW
[ 18 ] Scholarly Perspectives UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW
UCLA | SCHOOL OF LAW Scholarly Perspectives [ 19 ]