












































Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Prepare for your exams
Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points to download
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Community
Ask the community for help and clear up your study doubts
Discover the best universities in your country according to Docsity users
Free resources
Download our free guides on studying techniques, anxiety management strategies, and thesis advice from Docsity tutors
The relationship between vertical financial ownership and vertical contracting, arguing that they are essentially isomorphic phenomena. The paper also presents a theory for predicting and prescribing which form of organizational control will take in different environments, drawing on both transaction cost perspective and agency theory. references to various studies and literature on vertical integration and control.
What you will learn
Typology: Study notes
1 / 52
This page cannot be seen from the preview
Don't miss anything!
FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 89- College of Commerce and Business Administration University of Illinois at Urbana- Champaign December 1989 The Choice of Organizational Form: Vertical Integration versus other Methods of Vertical Control Joseph T. Mahoney Department of Business Administration University (^) of Illinois 1206 South Sixth Champaign, IL 61820 (217) 244-
The Choice of Organizational Form:
Abstract
strategic management and organizational^ economics.^ This^ paper synthesizes^ theoretical arguments
being seen as essentially isomorphic phenomena. The key theoretic question involves predicting when market mechanisms are sufficient, when intermediate forms of vertical contracting (^) become necessary, and when formal vertical integration is the preferred strategic (^) alternative. The
The Advantages of Vertical Integration An exhaustive review of the economic and strategy literature^ (Mahoney, 1989) suggests
monitoring, and enforcing buyer-supplier relationships^ (Jensen^ & Meckling,^ 1976). A^ good example of the potential cost savings of vertical merger is the avoidance of sales taxes when arms- length contracting is replaced by internal transfers (Coase, 1937). More subtly, vertically
(Bolch & Damon, 1978). Similar strategies can be found in other basic conversion industries such as copper, aluminum and steel (Scherer, (^) 1980). A second fundamental motive for vertical integration is the failure of markets to
include externalities (Dahlman, (^) 1979), increasing returns and sunk costs (Baumol, Panzar (^) & Willig,
Williamson, 1971) are^ some^ of^ the^ "institutions^ of^ capitalism"^ (Williamson,^ 1985)^ which^ emerged
Williamson's (1985) seminal^ research^ develops^ a^ well-grounded^ theoretical^ framework^ for explaining and predicting this market failure. The basic idea^ is^ that^ contractual^ difficulties^ arise when opportunistic agents (Anderson, 1988; Maitland, Byrson & Van De Ven, 1985) engage in
bounded rationality^ capabilities^ (Simon,^ 1978).^ The^ risk^ of^ self-interested^ agents^ utilizing
Williamson, 1975). Contractual problems become acute when^ there^ are^ small^ numbers bargaining, a situation that occurs when transactions involve human, physical or site "asset
machine tools and equipment. Site specificity occurs when unique locational advantages exist, (^) as, for example, when a power plant is located near a coal mine to save on transportation costs
supported (^) by a large (^) body of literature including case studies (Butler & Carney, 1983; Globerman & Schwindt, 1986; Goldberg & Erickson, (^) 1987; Hennart 1988b; Klein, Crawford & Alchian, (^) 1978; Palay, (^) 1984; Stuckey, (^) 1983; Teece, 1976), formal modeling (Kleindorfer & Knieps, 1982; Masten, 1982; Riordan & Williamson, 1985) and statistical testing (Anderson (^) & Schmittlein, (^) 1984; Armour & Teece,^ 1980; Caves & Bradburd, 1988; John & Weitz, 1988; Joskow, 1985a; Levy, (^) 1985; MacDonald, 1985; MacMillan, Hambrick (^) & Pennings, (^) 1986; Masten, 1984; Monteverde & Teece, 1982; Walker & Weber, 1984, 1987). A last important transaction (^) cost motive for vertical integration involves economies of scope (Baumol, (^) Panzar, & Willig, 1982; Teece 1980; Williamson, 1975), including technological complementarities (Bain, (^) 1968). The standard example (^) of vertical merger to achieve economies of
difficult for^ an^ oligopolist^ to^ plan^ secretly^ to^ increase^ market^ share.^ Since^ there^ were^ few significant independent^ refiners,^ no^ company^ could^ increase^ its^ output^ of^ crude^ oil^ without^ first
provide mobility barriers (Caves & Porter,^ 1977) which^ sustain^ the^ stability^ of^ strategic^ groups (McGee & Thomas,^ 1986; Newman,^ 1978).^ Differences^ between^ existing^ firms^ in^ their^ degree^ of
structure. Even more problematic, changes in vertical integration structure can^ increase^ the threat of entry as it^ has^ in^ steel^ (Adams^ &^ Dirlam,^ 1964), petroleum^ (de^ Chazeau^ &^ Kahn,^ 1959), and aluminum (Scherer, 1980).
firm, then there are several possible explanations^ for^ vertical^ integration.^ In^ the^ successive
"myopic chain monopoly" (Greenhut & Ohta, 1976). The essential idea is that the vertically
bargaining and resolves the conflict of the division of profits. The problem of firms being "locked in" (^) to a vertical (^) relationship is not uncommon (Klein, Crawford & Alchian, 1978).
additional (^) profits to the integrating monopolist (Mallela & Nahata, 1980; McGee & Bassett, 1976;
Schmalensee, 1973; Vernon^ &^ Graham,^ 1971;^ Waterson,^ 1982).^ Abiru^ (1988)^ extends^ this^ stream of literature to include the^ more^ empirically^ relevant^ case^ of^ variable-proportions^ technology^ and successive oligopolies. The price discrimination incentives for vertical integration can be elucidated by the example of an intermediate good monopolist^ selling^ to two^ downstream^ competitive^ industries. The upstream monopolist can^ increase^ profits^ by^ selling^ the^ intermediate^ product^ at^ a^ lower^ price to the^ downstream^ firm^ with^ the^ relatively^ higher^ price^ sensitivity^ (Perry,^ 1978).^ Vertical
product between the downstream firms. Perry (^) (1980) contends that forward integration by Alcoa
more price sensitive markets, such as cookware (Hale,^ 1967).
elements confronting the firm. Arrow (^) (1975) examined uncertainty in the supply price of the
downstream stages. A downstream firm has the incentive to purchase one or more upstream firms
uncertainty in demand and firms must make decisions concerning price and production before actual (^) demand is observable. In this case there is some risk of supply failure to the customer as
risk. Firms integrate (^) to ensure a supply of input for their "high probability" demand and continue
uncertainty of this type leads to vertical^ integration^ (Anderson^ &^ Schmittlein,^ 1984; Anderson, 1985). Measurement uncertainty and quality^ uncertainty^ are^ also^ important^ factors^ that^ lead^ to
apparent disagreement can be found in the literature. Armour^ and^ Teece^ (1980) argued that the
was due to market failures in information exchange. However,^ Harrigan (1986) and Walker & Weber (^) (1984, 1987) found that technological uncertainty was associated with (^) less vertical integration. The resolution of apparent disagreement here requires care to not confound (^) asset specificity and uncertainty. If technological uncertainty leads to the utilization of more flexible
The problems of recognition, disclosure, team organization and dissipation that are
integrate (Caves, (^) 1982; Teece, (^) 1982). The effect of technological uncertainty on vertical
substantial (^) interdependencies and were consequently produced in-house. The Walker and Weber
An Overview of Vertical Integration as a Corporate Strategy Uncertainty can take many forms. (i) Parametric or^ structural^ (Langlois,^ 1984). (ii) perceptual or market based (Downey, Hellriegel, & Slocum, 1975).
Williamson, 1975). As uncertainty^ increases,^ not^ only^ is^ the^ firm^ called^ into^ existence,^ there^ are
integration. More specifically, the same arguments found in the basic theory of the firm (Coase,
1983; Williamson,^ 1975). To ascertain the^ effect^ of^ increased^ "uncertainty"^ on^ vertical^ integration,^ however,
specificity (Anderson, 1985; Walker & Weber, 1984). Clearly, the economic and strategy literature has offered an impressive menu of advantages for the corporate strategy of vertical
(2) Coordination.^ The^ firm^ has^ better^ control^ of^ opportunistic^ behavior^ due^ to the
(3) Audit^ and^ Resource^ Allocation.^ The^ auditing^ powers^ of^ the^ firm^ are^ superior^ to the auditing capabilities of contracting parties (Williamson, 1975). A firm has the legal right to audit
use their (^) information strategically (to the detriment of the enterprise's profits) is eliminated
literature.
Insert TABLE 2 about here
loss and/or deliberate distortion to achieve divisional objectives (Calvo & Wellisz, 1978; Coase,
more costly than the market mechanism (Williamson, (^) 1985), undercutting the profit incentive for integration. One explanation (^) is that the lack of direct competitive pressures on the cost of the intermediate products may allow increasing levels of slack (Cyert & March, (^) 1963) and thus reduce (^) profitability. As firms vertically integrate away from the (^) base business, they are also likely to become involved in new manufacturing or selling tasks. Managing at the manufacturing and distribution
(1984), namely^ that^ vertical^ integration^ may^ result in a loss of access to information and tacit 11
knowledge as relationships^ with^ experienced^ and^ more^ broadly^ based^ distributorships^ are^ severed. A second potential strategic cost to vertical integration is that the firm purchases specialized assets
Panzar & Willig, 1982; Chandler, 1962; Rumelt, 1974). Third, vertical integration may link a firm to a weak adjacent industry^ (Harrigan,^ 1984)^ with^ an^ attendant^ loss^ in^ profitability.^ Fourth,
(Harrigan, 1985d). Production costs. Walker & Weber (1984) suggest that production costs are critical in the make-or-buy decision. A vertically integrated firm that does not utilize a sufficient amount of
& Wheelwright, 1984). Long-run dynamic (^) costs. The make-or-buy decision also must take into account
divisions face no competitive pressures for procurement. Even if outside sources exist as a
Second, (^) a norm of reciprocity (^) between divisions easily develops (Gouldner, 1960), and over time
commitment and (^) administrative difficulties of divestment (Duhaime & Grant, 1984; Duhaime & Schwenk, 1985) are important dynamic (^) costs that need (^) to be considered in the make-or-buy decision. 12